[1] Bickel W. K., Miller M. L., Yi R., Kowal B. P., Lindquist D. M., & Pitcock J. A. (2007). Behavioral and neuroeconomics of drug addiction: Competing neural systems and temporal discounting processes. Drug and Alcohol Dependence, 90(1), S85-S91. [2] Frederick, S., & Loewenstein, G. (2008). Conflicting motives in evaluations of sequences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 37(2), 221-235. [3] Frederick S., Loewenstein G., & O'Donoghue T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351-401. [4] Garcia A., Torrecillas M. J. M., & Rambaud S. C. (2020). The improving sequence effect on monetary sequences. Heliyon, 6(12), Article E05643. [5] Hershfield H. E., Goldstein D. G., Sharpe W. F., Fox J., Yeykelis L., Carstensen L. L., & Bailenson J. N. (2011). Increasing saving behavior through age-progressed renderings of the future self. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(SPL), S23-S37. [6] JASP Team. (2020). JASP (Version 0.13.1). https://jasp-stats.org/ [7] Jiang C. M., Sun H. M., Zhu L. F., Zhao L., Liu H. Z., & Sun H. Y. (2017). Better is worse, worse is better: Reexamination of violations of dominance in intertemporal choice. Judgment and Decision Making, 12(3), 253-259. [8] Johnson, M. W., & Bickel, W. K. (2002). Within-subject comparison of real and hypothetical money rewards in delay discounting. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 77(2), 129-146. [9] Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263-291. [10] Krantz, D. H., & Kunreuther, H. C. (2007). Goals and plans in decision making. Judgment and Decision Making, 2(3), 137-168. [11] Lempert, K. M., & Phelps, E. A. (2016). The malleability of intertemporal choice. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 20(1), 64-74. [12] Loewenstein, G., & Sicherman, N. (1991). Do workers prefer increasing wage profiles? Journal of Labor Economics, 9(1), 67-84. [13] Loewenstein, G. F., & Prelec, D. (1991). Negative time preference. American Economic Review, 81(2), 347-352. [14] Loewenstein, G. F., & Prelec, D. (1993). Preferences for sequences of outcomes. Psychological Review, 100(1), 91-108. [15] Madden G. J., Begotka A. M., Raiff B. R., & Kastern L. L. (2003). Delay discounting of real and hypothetical rewards. Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology, 11(2), 139-145. [16] Scholten M., Read D., & Sanborn A. (2016). Cumulative weighing of time in intertemporal tradeoffs. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 145(9), 1177-1205. [17] Thaler, R. (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Economics Letters, 8(3), 201-207. [18] Urminsky, O., & Kivetz, R. (2011). Scope insensitivity and the "mere token" effect. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(2), 282-295. [19] Warren C., McGraw A. P., & van Boven L. (2011). Values and preferences: Defining preference construction. WIREs Cognitive Science, 2(2), 193-205. [20] Wilson, J. M. (2021). Financial literacy, experience, and age differences in monetary sequence preferences (Unpublished master's thesis). West Virginia University. |